Bob Carr should stop referring to “economic refugees”. The term is a legal misnomer. Under the 1951 Convention relating to the Status of Refugees, there is no recognition of so-called “economic refugees”. The Foreign Minister's use of the term is therefore disingenuous, because it is inconceivable that he is ignorant of what the Convention defines as a refugee.
During Question Time in the Senate last Thursday, the Foreign Minister said, in reference to asylum seekers from Iran arriving in Australia by boat, that increasingly, the “evidence before us is they are economic refugees, not people fleeing persecution, and are being brought here by people-smugglers”. The Foreign Minister also referred to these asylum seekers as “overwhelmingly middle-class … who belong to the majority religious and ethnic group in that country and are coming to these shores as economic migrants...”
First, under Article 1 of the Refugee Convention, a “refugee” is someone who, owing to a well-founded fear of being persecuted for reasons of race, religion, nationality, membership of a particular social group or political opinion, is outside the country of his nationality and is unable or, owing to such fear, is unwilling to available himself of the protection of that country.
These five grounds are the only grounds on which a claim for asylum may be made. Claims based on economic hardship or the want of a 'better' life will not be recognised under the Refugee Convention. If this is the basis of an asylum claim, that claim will fail. For this reason, it is simply wrong to speak of “economic refugees”. They cannot exist by definition. It is also misleading for the Foreign Minister to suggest that people who are “middle-class” or belong to the majority cannot be genuine refugees. Nowhere in the definition of a refugee is there any requirement to demonstrate poverty or membership of a minority religion or ethnic group. It is wrong of the Foreign Minister to play on misguided preconceptions and prejudices held against asylum seekers.
If a person satisfies the definition of a “refugee” then he or she is given refugee status under the Convention. This means that people arriving in Australia, seeking asylum have a right to make a claim for protection. It is wrong to speak of them as “illegal arrivals”. The Convention does not say anything about the means of arrival. Therefore, politicians may demonise boat arrivals as they like but it has no basis in law. An asylum seeker is free to chose their mode of arrival. When we consider the requirement that a person seeking asylum must demonstrate a well-founded fear of being persecuted, accusations of “queue jumping” and the absence of proper travel documentation are absurds notions. If a person is a genuine refugee, then they will have fled their country for fear of persecution, meaning threat to life or freedom and serious violation of one's human rights. Indeed, the Convention actually requires a refugee to have left their country owing to their fear of that persecution.
The Foreign Minister's deployment of the term “economic refugees” is scaremongering and demonising; it appeals to those of us who might think there are refugees who do not deserve to be here, who have come for a better life, when there is not enough of the pie to go around, as it is. Each time the term “economic refugee” is used, those of us who know better or should know better (including the media) have an obligation to challenge and resist that use, because it is the right thing to do, morally and legally.
Wednesday, 3 July 2013
Tuesday, 18 June 2013
The Trivialisation of Domestic Violence
In the past two days, much has been written about the public attack of Nigella Lawson by her husband, Charles Saatchi. Photos now circulating media outlets capture the celebrity cook in a moment of unmistakable fear and distress. It is perhaps emblematic of the culture and times we live in, that it takes something like this to happen to a celebrity to capture the world's attention on what is in fact, one of our most profound social problems. On another level, the colliding of fame, wealth, beauty and success with the ugly face of abuse exposes the prejudices and judgements we harbour about what domestic violence looks like. According to women's support organisation, Wire (www.wire.org.au) one in five women will be affected by family violence at some time during their life. According to a 2005 survey undertaken by the Australian Bureau of Statistics, incredibly, more than one million women had experienced physical or sexual assault by their male current or ex-partner since the age of 15 and 64% of women who experienced physical assault and 81.1% of women who experienced sexual assault did not make a police report.
I read today that Saatchi has received a warning from police over the incident. Saatchi has been reported as describing the incident as "playful tiff", over a heated discussion about the couple's children. Saatchi has reportedly said that he held Lawson's neck repeatedly to emphasis his point. We should remember that for most of the Western world (including Australia), it was not so long ago that marital rape was a contested notion, and a husband was considered entitled to engage in a bit of harmless horseplay in exercising his right to conjugal relations with his wife. Legal and social opinion has moved a long way from archaic notions of woman as property, but this episode shows that these attitudes are not dead and buried. Indeed, it is in our attitudes towards defining what constitutes abuse that we find the many silences that persist.
It is trite to say that there was nothing playful or benign about the exchange between Saatchi and Lawson. We bore witness to something that should not only shock us, but anger us. We should be angered by what Saatchi purports to do through his casual and dismissive language in describing the incident as playful tiff. Saatchi showed himself not only willing to inflict fear upon the person with whom he shares a home and a life, but also an utter lack of disrespect towards her. He did so flagrantly, and in his subsequent trivialisation of his conduct, he has sought to dismiss and silence, not only his critics but also his victim.
I read today that Saatchi has received a warning from police over the incident. Saatchi has been reported as describing the incident as "playful tiff", over a heated discussion about the couple's children. Saatchi has reportedly said that he held Lawson's neck repeatedly to emphasis his point. We should remember that for most of the Western world (including Australia), it was not so long ago that marital rape was a contested notion, and a husband was considered entitled to engage in a bit of harmless horseplay in exercising his right to conjugal relations with his wife. Legal and social opinion has moved a long way from archaic notions of woman as property, but this episode shows that these attitudes are not dead and buried. Indeed, it is in our attitudes towards defining what constitutes abuse that we find the many silences that persist.
It is trite to say that there was nothing playful or benign about the exchange between Saatchi and Lawson. We bore witness to something that should not only shock us, but anger us. We should be angered by what Saatchi purports to do through his casual and dismissive language in describing the incident as playful tiff. Saatchi showed himself not only willing to inflict fear upon the person with whom he shares a home and a life, but also an utter lack of disrespect towards her. He did so flagrantly, and in his subsequent trivialisation of his conduct, he has sought to dismiss and silence, not only his critics but also his victim.
Monday, 17 June 2013
On Sexism and the Politics of Gender
It was a big week in gender politics last week to say the least. On Tuesday, Julia Gillard reignited the so-called 'gender wars', warning, at the launch of 'Women for Gillard', that an Abbott government would threaten women's political participation and abortion rights. Perhaps not surprisingly, this play was viewed by many as a somewhat desperate and disingenuous attempt by the Prime Minister to use gender to divert attention from the polling woes of the Labor government. The next day, details were leaked of an LNP fundraiser for Liberal candidate Mal Brough, listing as a menu item, ‘‘Julia Gillard Kentucky Fried Quail’’ described as ‘‘small breasts, huge thighs & a big red box’’. Sexist, distasteful and downright nasty. On Thursday, shocking revelations of an internet sex ring within the Australian Defence Force, men filming women engaged in sexually explicit acts, the Chief of Army confronting the exploitation, humiliation and degradation of women by those within the armed forces.
To cap the week off, radio host Howard Sattler, saw fit to question the Prime Minister on the sexuality of her partner, Tim Mathieson. Sattler has been roundly condemned, and I believe, quite rightly, sacked from 6PR. I watched the footage published by The Age of the interview segment. Whether you are a 'feminist' or not; the way in which Sattler carried out his questioning of the Prime Minister on her partner's sexuality based on supposed rumour was a pure performance in sexism and misogyny. It was a deeply personal attack; with no real point to the whole thing, other than Sattler's desire to humiliate the Prime Minister. And what a crude way to humiliate and embarrass, through the suggestion of homosexuality, which for Sattler, serves as a smear on both their sexualities, a profoundly private matter. In the exchange of body language between the Prime Minister and Sattler, there was also a telling story. Sattler performs his role as macho shock jock to perfection; knowing and savouring that he has caught the Prime Minister in a trap; her embarrassment is palpable. Yet still, I saw the Prime Minister of Australia, by all accounts a strong and capable women, trying to placate an offensive and vitriolic man; the peace-maker, seeking to 'smooth things over'. Julia Gillard might have rightly been criticised for gender opportunism, and her motives for reigniting the gender war questioned; but the Sattler episode shows us that sexism and misogyny is well and alive and the Prime Minister should not be criticised for making gender a topic of public discourse.
To cap the week off, radio host Howard Sattler, saw fit to question the Prime Minister on the sexuality of her partner, Tim Mathieson. Sattler has been roundly condemned, and I believe, quite rightly, sacked from 6PR. I watched the footage published by The Age of the interview segment. Whether you are a 'feminist' or not; the way in which Sattler carried out his questioning of the Prime Minister on her partner's sexuality based on supposed rumour was a pure performance in sexism and misogyny. It was a deeply personal attack; with no real point to the whole thing, other than Sattler's desire to humiliate the Prime Minister. And what a crude way to humiliate and embarrass, through the suggestion of homosexuality, which for Sattler, serves as a smear on both their sexualities, a profoundly private matter. In the exchange of body language between the Prime Minister and Sattler, there was also a telling story. Sattler performs his role as macho shock jock to perfection; knowing and savouring that he has caught the Prime Minister in a trap; her embarrassment is palpable. Yet still, I saw the Prime Minister of Australia, by all accounts a strong and capable women, trying to placate an offensive and vitriolic man; the peace-maker, seeking to 'smooth things over'. Julia Gillard might have rightly been criticised for gender opportunism, and her motives for reigniting the gender war questioned; but the Sattler episode shows us that sexism and misogyny is well and alive and the Prime Minister should not be criticised for making gender a topic of public discourse.
Monday, 10 June 2013
Certiorari
Certiorari was established in 2013 as a place to express, share and promote the exchange of exciting and provoking ideas and conversations. Comments are most welcome at: certiorari.blogspot@gmail.com
Friday, 7 June 2013
A review of Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty by Abhijit V. Banerjee and Esther Duflo
In
Poor
Economics,
Abhijit
Banerjee and Esther Duflo put forward an alternative way of thinking
about the fight against global poverty. They posit that global
poverty will not be solved by debating the big ideological questions
around world poverty; questions such as, what is the cause of
poverty? does aid really work? should we put our faith in free
markets? As a consequence, they reject emphatically, any notion that
the development project of lifting the poor out of poverty can be
furthered by engaging with the orthodox contest between aid versus
market solutions or supply versus demand (as exemplified by Jeffrey
Sachs and William Easterly). Indeed, Banerjee and Duflo reject the
notion that ideology can lead us down the path to the 'right'
answers.
Banerjee
and Duflo's approach seems seductively simple. Their re-thinking is
essentially two fold. First, dealing with the ideological question,
they say it is necessary to break down the big questions about global
poverty into smaller questions; that is, to think of concrete
problems with specific answers. The task is then to gather empirical
evidence to find answers to those problems, identifying the best way
of solving these problems. To do this, Banerjee and Duflo have
advocated the use of randomised controlled trials or 'RCTs'; large
scale experiments first used in the medical field to test the
effectiveness of new drugs. In an RCT, individuals or communities
are randomly assigned different treatments or different versions of
the same treatment, to test the effectiveness of the treatment or
perhaps, the method of delivery of the treatment. Since the
individuals or communities chosen are exactly comparable, any
differentiation in results can be attributed to the treatment itself.
Although Banerjee and Duflo say there are no 'magic bullet'
solutions to fighting poverty, they say that RCTs are one way in
which the effectiveness of social policy can be tested. Banerjee and
Duflo believe that by placing policies and programmes under rigorous
scrutiny, we can begin to avoid making social policy based on guess
work and faith in an ideology. Banerjee and Duflo are not however,
mere advocates of RCTs; they have for over a decade, championed its
use as the new way of 'doing' developmental economics. Together,
Banerjee and Duflo founded the Poverty Action Lab or J-PAL at the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology in 2003 and by 2010, J-PAL had
completed or engaged in over 240 experiments in forty countries.
Poor
Economics documents
Banerjee and Duflo's admirable dedication to tackling global poverty
through a patient and meticulous process of evidence gathering, one
experiment at a time. It is also a testament to Banerjee and Duflo's
commitment to seeking to understand real problems faced by the poor
and how the poor make decisions about their daily lives. In short,
they are passionate and they evince good intentions. Poor
Economics is
a detailed, but very engaging account of the work Banerjee and Duflo
have done through J-PAL and in an eighteen country data set, to
systematically and methodically test (and therefore challenge)
particular applications of the big 'projects' within the global
poverty and development. Thus, the book dedicates one chapter to
each of these projects, namely, food, health, education, population
and family planning, insurance, credit, savings, entrepreneurship and
institutional and political reform. Banerjee and Duflo's ultimate
message is that there are no miracle solutions to eradicate global
poverty, but by studiously examining the lives of the poor and the
poverty traps which effect them, it is possible to create change
slowly, by implementing small, well planned and well tested steps; or
in their words, 'nudges' in the right direction.
It
is easy to be somewhat taken in by the combination of the ease of
Banerjee and Duflo's narrative style, the seeming accessibility of
economics and statistics as explained in Poor Economics and
Banerjee and Duflo's commitment to a “grassroots” approach to
doing development. One is also persuaded (naturally) by the eminent
sensibility of demanding evidence for policies and programmes;
'proof' as it were, that something works before a wholesale
dedication to the idea based on faith of ideology. But underneath or
perhaps beyond this, there are some interesting and perhaps,
uncomfortable themes in operation.
The
accessible tone of Banerjee and Duflo's narrative style seems to
invoke a sense of inclusion. But inclusion of whom? The 'we' and the
'our' in Banerjee and Duflo's narrative is decidedly they themselves
(the authors) and us (the readership). Problematically, the poor,
remain always, the subject of study and examination; they are never
active
participants in this narrative, despite the myriad of stories and
rich insights into the lives of the poor portrayed in Poor
Economics.
In this interpretation of Banerjee and Duflo's narrative, RCTs are
devised, implemented and concluded from above and outside. As such,
one might see the poor, represented in Poor
Economics
always as the inactive, depoliticised Other.
There
is thus a silent paternalism in Poor
Economics
which raises important notions concerning consent. Poor
Economics appears
to imply consent of participants in the RCTs about which Banerjee and
Duflo write. This invites the question of the nature of consent.
Whilst it might readily be accepted that participants gave their
formal consent to experiments, the issue is not quite so clear when
we turn to the question of the true nature of consent. There is
a presumption that there is consent to the presence of we/us (the
development workers, the economists and even the readership). On
closer examination, behind the narrative of Poor
Economics,
is a very active and intrusive process of interference; we are
intruding as it were, into the lives of the poor, dissecting,
examining, observing and moreover, measuring and judging, using our
terms, our measures and our values. On a more basic level, there is
the question of true consent to experimentation itself. Paternalism
is in fact raised by Banerjee and Duflo in their chapter on health
care, and arguably, rather unsatisfactorily dealt with. Rather than
engage with the problem of paternalism, Banerjee and Duflo appear to
merely accept that there is paternalism in the development enterprise
and say, it is easy to sermonise about paternalism from the comfort
of our couches, but that we of the rich world are beneficiaries of
embedded paternalism and its resultant virtues. That seems somewhat
a reductive and circular argument.
Operating
at an overarching level is an ascendant economic narrative. It is
perfectly reasonable for a book written by development economists,
about development economics and what it has to say about world
poverty to be decidedly economics-centric. But it raises the
interesting consideration, to what degree does such focus then
exclude other discourses which might have something to say about the
lives of the poor? It is noted that particularly in this context,
this notion of 'the poor' is itself hugely problematic, notably but
not in the least, for its implication of (false) hegemony and
universality. In Banerjee and Duflo's narrative, people and
communities unavoidably become ultimately absorbed within a large
social experiment. They are consequently collated; into data,
outcomes and then finally, bodies of statistics for further
examination and judgment. This is not to say that Banerjee and Duflo
do not engage with the social and the cultural; indeed, Poor
Economics evidences
quite the opposite. Banerjee and Duflo report, time and again on the
impact that cultural practices and beliefs have on economic decisions
made by the poor. The point is, that there is something
discomforting in Banerjee and Duflo eschewing big philosophies on the
one hand, and arguably embracing another philosophy of economic
determinism on the other.
Finally,
the question of ethics, connected to the notion of the absence of
participation and true consent. Randomised controlled trials in this
context necessarily entails the taking
of real human subjects and experimenting with aspects of their lives.
In the case of RCTs described in Poor
Economics,
those conducting the experiments seemingly devise and carry out the
experiments. There are deeply problematic ethical issues surrounding
the giving of one group a 'beneficial' treatment and depriving
another of the same and indeed, experimentation with real lives, for
observational purposes, justified on the assumption that ultimately,
'we' (the development industry) want what is best for the poor.
Banerjee and Duflo do not address the ethical question, and
consequently, there is seemingly (and regrettably) a sense that the
evident vulnerability of the poor we meet in Poor
Economics
vis-a-vis the authors and the bigger development enterprise is
ignored. Put another way, there is an apparent failure on the part
of Banerjee and Duflo to acknowledge (or perhaps, recognise) the
power structures which underlie their very narrative. There is no
reflection upon the very fact of power which the development
enterprise holds over the supposed beneficiaries of the project.
From this perspective, there is a hidden process within Poor
Economics which
operates and disempowers its subject.
Poor
Economics is not short of achievements. Banerjee and Duflo
succeed in their objective, to show how fighting global poverty could
be done differently and they certainly provide passionate and rich
insights into the lives of the poor. Poor Economics invites
us into the lives of the poor and therefore, the development
enterprise. Therefore, we, the critical reader should, in accepting
this invitation, examine and acknowledge the more difficult issues
within and around Poor Economics.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)